Inter-American Development Bank
facebook
twitter
youtube
linkedin
instagram
Abierto al públicoBeyond BordersCaribbean Development TrendsCiudades SosteniblesEnergía para el FuturoEnfoque EducaciónFactor TrabajoGente SaludableGestión fiscalGobernarteIdeas MatterIdeas que CuentanIdeaçãoImpactoIndustrias CreativasLa Maleta AbiertaMoviliblogMás Allá de las FronterasNegocios SosteniblesPrimeros PasosPuntos sobre la iSeguridad CiudadanaSostenibilidadVolvamos a la fuente¿Y si hablamos de igualdad?Home
Citizen Security and Justice Creative Industries Development Effectiveness Early Childhood Development Education Energy Envirnment. Climate Change and Safeguards Fiscal policy and management Gender and Diversity Health Labor and pensions Open Knowledge Public management Science, Technology and Innovation  Trade and Regional Integration Urban Development and Housing Water and Sanitation
  • Skip to main content
  • Skip to secondary menu
  • Skip to primary sidebar
  • Skip to footer

Ideas Matter

  • HOME
  • CATEGORIES
    • Behavioral Economics
    • Environment and Climate Change
    • Macroeconomics and Finance
    • Microeconomics and Competitiveness
    • Politics and Institutions
    • Social Issues
  • Authors
  • Spanish

Can New Methods Sharpen Targeting in Programs for the Poor?

October 20, 2016 by Bridget Hoffmann Leave a Comment


In recent years, developing countries have struggled to make social welfare programs for the poor and vulnerable more efficient. The distribution of preventative health products is an important example. Such products can help the poor stave off malnutrition and disease and improve overall productivity. But they have traditionally been distributed using subsidized pricing, and while that can increase coverage, it is also likely to screen out the poor, who lack the same access to cash, savings, and credit as the relatively rich. The challenge of improving targeting is critical.

How can targeting be improved? Directly targeting the poor to receive a subsidy is not possible without widespread, accurate documentation of income. I propose an alternative mechanism, which is the subject of a new IDB study, using non-monetary prices, such as making people wait in line or perform some kind of work in exchange for the health product. This makes sense intuitively if the poor are more willing to pay in time than the rich.

The answer, however, is not so simple. This is because each hour spent working in exchange for the health product (paying a non-monetary price) could have been spent working for a wage. And economic theory demonstrates two opposing effects of a higher wage. On the one hand, higher wages mean that each hour spent to pay a non-monetary price results in a greater number of foregone goods, so foregoing monetary wages to pay a non-monetary price is especially costly for the rich. On the other hand, because of the wealthier starting point that households with higher wages enjoy, each additional hour’s wage is less critical. So, from that perspective, the rich would be more likely than the poor to purchase the health product at a non-monetary price.

Since economic theory alone cannot answer this question, I designed a field experiment to empirically test whether non-monetary prices better target health products to the poor than monetary prices. The experiment took place in Hyderabad, India using a locally available water purifier. Water contamination is a persistent public health concern in Hyderabad. The Central Pollution Board determined that tap water must be treated and disinfected before it is considered safe for drinking. But data collected at the outset of the study revealed that 70% of the 800 households across 17 low-income neighborhoods didn’t own a water purifier. The risks from drinking untreated water are substantial. In 2013, the year in which the experiment was conducted, over 100 people died from water borne diseases in Andhra Pradesh, the state in which Hyderabad was located (Hyderabad is now in the state of Telegana).

The experiment determined each household’s willingness to pay for a water purifier at a non-monetary price (hours spent sorting seeds) and at a monetary price (cash). Combining these two measures of willingness to pay with data collected during the household survey, I estimated demand curves for each price type and determined which type of price results in the greatest percentage of water purifiers in the hands of the poor.

I find that a 10% increase in household income resulted in a 2% increase in the amount that households were willing to pay in cash. So if the water purifier were offered for a monetary price, a greater number of relatively rich households would purchase it than poor households. But if it were offered for a non-monetary price, the proportion of poor households who purchase the water purifier would increase to at least the same level as the rich. While far from precise targeting, this means that requiring people to dedicate their time and effort in exchange for a health product hones in on the needy significantly more effectively than using a cash price.

A few other recent studies have also demonstrated the significant potential of non-monetary prices for policymakers. For example, work by Rema Hanna and her coauthors finds that requiring time and effort by potential beneficiaries can greatly improve the targeting of cash transfers to the poor in Indonesia. Non-monetary price mechanisms may not be necessary in those Latin American countries where there is accurate documentation of people’s income and government programs function well. But in countries where it is difficult to identify and verify who is in fact poor, non-monetary prices can improve targeting and help deliver a greater proportion of resources to those who need them most.


Filed Under: Macroeconomics and Finance, Social Issues Tagged With: #health, #poverty, #SocialPolicy

Bridget Hoffmann

Bridget Hoffmann is an economist in the Research Department of the Inter-American Development Bank. Her research interests are applied microeconomics, development economics, and environmental economics. She received her Ph.D. in Economics from Northwestern University in 2015. She holds a bachelor’s degree in Financial Economics and Mathematics from the University of Rochester.

Reader Interactions

Leave a Reply Cancel reply

Your email address will not be published. Required fields are marked *

Primary Sidebar

Follow Us

Subscribe

Search

Related posts

  • Promoting Competition to Boost Welfare Through Social Programs
  • Can Cash Transfers to Non-Poor Households Prevent Poverty?
  • Inflation and Its Impact on the Poor in the Era of COVID-19
  • Big Data and the Pursuit of Better Disaster Relief
  • Covid-19: The Challenge of Ensuring Assistance to Informal and Vulnerable Workers

About this blog

The blog of the IDB's Research Department shares ideas that matter on public policy and development in Latin America and the Caribbean.

Footer

Banco Interamericano de Desarrollo
facebook
twitter
youtube
youtube
youtube

    Blog posts written by Bank employees:

    Copyright © Inter-American Development Bank ("IDB"). This work is licensed under a Creative Commons IGO 3.0 Attribution-NonCommercial-NoDerivatives. (CC-IGO 3.0 BY-NC-ND) license and may be reproduced with attribution to the IDB and for any non-commercial purpose. No derivative work is allowed. Any dispute related to the use of the works of the IDB that cannot be settled amicably shall be submitted to arbitration pursuant to the UNCITRAL rules. The use of the IDB's name for any purpose other than for attribution, and the use of IDB's logo shall be subject to a separate written license agreement between the IDB and the user and is not authorized as part of this CC- IGO license. Note that link provided above includes additional terms and conditions of the license.


    For blogs written by external parties:

    For questions concerning copyright for authors that are not IADB employees please complete the contact form for this blog.

    The opinions expressed in this blog are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the views of the IDB, its Board of Directors, or the countries they represent.

    Attribution: in addition to giving attribution to the respective author and copyright owner, as appropriate, we would appreciate if you could include a link that remits back the IDB Blogs website.



    Privacy Policy

    Copyright © 2025 · Magazine Pro on Genesis Framework · WordPress · Log in

    Banco Interamericano de Desarrollo

    Aviso Legal

    Las opiniones expresadas en estos blogs son las de los autores y no necesariamente reflejan las opiniones del Banco Interamericano de Desarrollo, sus directivas, la Asamblea de Gobernadores o sus países miembros.

    facebook
    twitter
    youtube
    This site uses cookies to optimize functionality and give you the best possible experience. If you continue to navigate this website beyond this page, cookies will be placed on your browser.
    To learn more about cookies, click here
    X
    Manage consent

    Privacy Overview

    This website uses cookies to improve your experience while you navigate through the website. Out of these, the cookies that are categorized as necessary are stored on your browser as they are essential for the working of basic functionalities of the website. We also use third-party cookies that help us analyze and understand how you use this website. These cookies will be stored in your browser only with your consent. You also have the option to opt-out of these cookies. But opting out of some of these cookies may affect your browsing experience.
    Necessary
    Always Enabled
    Necessary cookies are absolutely essential for the website to function properly. This category only includes cookies that ensures basic functionalities and security features of the website. These cookies do not store any personal information.
    Non-necessary
    Any cookies that may not be particularly necessary for the website to function and is used specifically to collect user personal data via analytics, ads, other embedded contents are termed as non-necessary cookies. It is mandatory to procure user consent prior to running these cookies on your website.
    SAVE & ACCEPT