Inter-American Development Bank
facebook
twitter
youtube
linkedin
instagram
Abierto al públicoBeyond BordersCaribbean Development TrendsCiudades SosteniblesEnergía para el FuturoEnfoque EducaciónFactor TrabajoGente SaludableGestión fiscalGobernarteIdeas MatterIdeas que CuentanIdeaçãoImpactoIndustrias CreativasLa Maleta AbiertaMoviliblogMás Allá de las FronterasNegocios SosteniblesPrimeros PasosPuntos sobre la iSeguridad CiudadanaSostenibilidadVolvamos a la fuente¿Y si hablamos de igualdad?Home
Citizen Security and Justice Creative Industries Development Effectiveness Early Childhood Development Education Energy Envirnment. Climate Change and Safeguards Fiscal policy and management Gender and Diversity Health Labor and pensions Open Knowledge Public management Science, Technology and Innovation  Trade and Regional Integration Urban Development and Housing Water and Sanitation
  • Skip to main content
  • Skip to secondary menu
  • Skip to primary sidebar
  • Skip to footer

Ideas Matter

  • HOME
  • CATEGORIES
    • Behavioral Economics
    • Environment and Climate Change
    • Macroeconomics and Finance
    • Microeconomics and Competitiveness
    • Politics and Institutions
    • Social Issues
  • Authors
  • Spanish

Fiscal Procyclicality? Bad Luck or Bad Decisions?

November 23, 2015 by Research Department Leave a Comment



By Leopoldo Avellan and Guillermo Vuletin*

Has it ever happened to you that by mid-year, when looking through the household bills you realize that your income is not what you expected, so you have to postpone the car you had planned to buy, give up that vacation you had promised your family, and even change the kids’ school you thought you could afford? Such decisions definitely do not go down well at home. Imagine now that this situation is repeated every year. Your children could say you have a problem of over-optimism, because you can never do what you promise, and end up cutting down your expenses because you overestimate your income. In your defense you can argue that it’s not your fault, that it’s very difficult to project income and you did not expect it to fall. Or maybe they tell you that this systematic cut in spending when your income falls is on purpose. You can counter that this accusation is unfair because it is based on information on your income you did not have when you made ​​the original spending plan, and that in reality they should base their evaluation on the real time information available at the time of planning.

Governments go through the same thing, with the aggravation that they can make things much worse if they cut spending just when the economy is contracting, or they can make the situation more exuberant if they increase spending when the economy is buoyant. This peculiarity in government spending – procyclicality – is empirically established for developing countries and has a number of explanations. As in the example of family budgets, and in favor of those who make the spending decisions, over-optimism and the suggested use of real-time data have appeared as recent explanations for this problem. These arguments have gained ground lately among academics and policymakers because most economies in the world have revised their growth estimates multiple times since the so-called Global Crisis of 2008.

The over-optimism hypothesis states that fiscal policy ends up being procyclical, not because policymakers wish it but because it is difficult to correctly predict economic growth. The idea is that, in principle, when formulating spending plans, optimism invites the belief that economic growth will be greater, so a program of higher spending is proposed. One solution to this problem is to design mechanisms that produce the best possible forecasts for economic growth.

The real-time information hypothesis, in contrast, proposes that policymakers are fundamentally countercyclical when designing fiscal policy. However, later adjustments in the wake of unexpected economic fluctuations give the false impression of procyclicality. So it is “unfair” to judge public officials with something over which in practice they had no control or did not expect when planning fiscal policy.

In a recent study, Avellan and Vuletin show that neither ingenuous prediction of output (over-optimism), nor an unfair evaluation of spending decisions that does not incorporate real-time information can explain fiscal procyclicality in developing countries. What really matters are the institutions that influence how economies manage public spending in relation to surprise fluctuations in output.

First, over-optimism in itself says nothing about the procyclicality of fiscal policy. What determines if spending is procyclical is not, therefore, the accuracy of the economic growth forecast, but the systematically positive relationship between spending and the surprise component of output growth. For example, the data shows that both industrial and developing countries have on average the same “over-optimism;” however, industrial countries are not procyclical like developing countries, because in the latter public spending moves along with surprise growth.

Second, the unfairness of not using the information available to policymakers is not the explanation either. Since in the end countries are procyclical, the only way policymakers are initially countercyclical when formulating fiscal policy is if there is a positive systematic relationship between spending and the surprise component of output. In other words, if they behave procyclically in relation to surprise economic growth, how then can they be so virtuous at the time of planning spending, but then fall into the trap of moving spending along with surprise growth?

So if neither of the hypotheses – over-optimism or use of real-time information – appears to be valid, what is the fundamental difference that makes developing countries procyclical while their industrial counterparts are not? It is precisely strong institutions and arguments of political economy that determine how spending relates to surprise fluctuations in economic growth. The evidence suggests that indices of institutional quality and checks and balances are the crux of how fiscal policy is managed in the face of unexpected changes in growth.

In other words, although actions to improve the capacity to forecast output and reduce over-optimism are important, efforts to support the independence of the different branches of government, the quality of the bureaucracy and government efficiency are at the core of reducing the procyclicality of fiscal policy. In other words, instead of asking for better projections, policymakers should demand better institutions.

_______

Leopoldo Avellan:  Economics Profesor at the Faculty of Economics and Business ( FEN ) and Graduate School of Business Administration ( ESPAE ) ESPOL. Director of the Center for Economic Research ( CIEC ) of ESPOL. Contry Economist for the IDB economist. Ph.D. in Economics , University of Maryland (2005 ) Master in Economics, University of Maryland (2002 ) Master in Economics, University Pompeu Fabra , Barcelona (2000 ) Economist, ESPOL , 1998.

 

Guillermo Vuletin: Nonresident Fellow in the Global Economy and Development Program at the Brookings Institution. He is also a Visiting Economist in the Research Department at the Inter-American Development Bank and Visiting Professor at the Johns Hopkins School of Advanced International Studies (SAIS). He received a PhD in Economics from the University of Maryland in 2007 and an undergraduate degree and a MA in Economics from the Universidad Nacional de La Plata, Argentina.
His research focuses on fiscal and monetary policies with a particular interest in macroeconomic policy in emerging and developing countries.  His work has been featured in the financial press, including The Economist, The Financial Times, and The Washington Post.

Filed Under: Macroeconomics and Finance Tagged With: #macroeconomics

Research Department

Reader Interactions

Leave a Reply Cancel reply

Your email address will not be published. Required fields are marked *

Primary Sidebar

Follow Us

Subscribe

Search

Related posts

  • Fiscal Rules for Commodity-Dependent Economies
  • Fiscal Transfers in Latin America: Red de Centros Is Calling for Proposals
  • Joseph and the Seven Cows: A Parable for Latin America and the Caribbean
  • Fiscal Rules for a Debt-Plagued Region
  • Preserving Public Investment During Fiscal Adjustments

About this blog

The blog of the IDB's Research Department shares ideas that matter on public policy and development in Latin America and the Caribbean.

Footer

Banco Interamericano de Desarrollo
facebook
twitter
youtube
youtube
youtube

    Blog posts written by Bank employees:

    Copyright © Inter-American Development Bank ("IDB"). This work is licensed under a Creative Commons IGO 3.0 Attribution-NonCommercial-NoDerivatives. (CC-IGO 3.0 BY-NC-ND) license and may be reproduced with attribution to the IDB and for any non-commercial purpose. No derivative work is allowed. Any dispute related to the use of the works of the IDB that cannot be settled amicably shall be submitted to arbitration pursuant to the UNCITRAL rules. The use of the IDB's name for any purpose other than for attribution, and the use of IDB's logo shall be subject to a separate written license agreement between the IDB and the user and is not authorized as part of this CC- IGO license. Note that link provided above includes additional terms and conditions of the license.


    For blogs written by external parties:

    For questions concerning copyright for authors that are not IADB employees please complete the contact form for this blog.

    The opinions expressed in this blog are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the views of the IDB, its Board of Directors, or the countries they represent.

    Attribution: in addition to giving attribution to the respective author and copyright owner, as appropriate, we would appreciate if you could include a link that remits back the IDB Blogs website.



    Privacy Policy

    Copyright © 2025 · Magazine Pro on Genesis Framework · WordPress · Log in

    Banco Interamericano de Desarrollo

    Aviso Legal

    Las opiniones expresadas en estos blogs son las de los autores y no necesariamente reflejan las opiniones del Banco Interamericano de Desarrollo, sus directivas, la Asamblea de Gobernadores o sus países miembros.

    facebook
    twitter
    youtube
    This site uses cookies to optimize functionality and give you the best possible experience. If you continue to navigate this website beyond this page, cookies will be placed on your browser.
    To learn more about cookies, click here
    X
    Manage consent

    Privacy Overview

    This website uses cookies to improve your experience while you navigate through the website. Out of these, the cookies that are categorized as necessary are stored on your browser as they are essential for the working of basic functionalities of the website. We also use third-party cookies that help us analyze and understand how you use this website. These cookies will be stored in your browser only with your consent. You also have the option to opt-out of these cookies. But opting out of some of these cookies may affect your browsing experience.
    Necessary
    Always Enabled
    Necessary cookies are absolutely essential for the website to function properly. This category only includes cookies that ensures basic functionalities and security features of the website. These cookies do not store any personal information.
    Non-necessary
    Any cookies that may not be particularly necessary for the website to function and is used specifically to collect user personal data via analytics, ads, other embedded contents are termed as non-necessary cookies. It is mandatory to procure user consent prior to running these cookies on your website.
    SAVE & ACCEPT